Economic Reform versus Rent Seeking
Anders Åslund and Mikhail Dmitriev
On August 17, 1998, Russia faced financial collapse. The government
devalued the ruble, defaulted on its domestic treasury bills, and proclaimed
a 90-day moratorium on its foreign debt payments. The ruble exchange rate
quickly fell to one-third of its prior value. Within a week President Boris
Yeltsin dismissed the reformist government headed by Sergei Kiriyenko, in
effect for failing to secure Duma approval of measures that might have prevented
the crisis. In the month of September, inflation rose to 38 percent per month,
contributing to an annual inflation rate of 84 percent in 1998. The bank and
payments system collapsed. As a result, the Russian gross domestic product
(GDP) fell by 4.6 percent in 1998 (with a similar contraction expected in
1999). As of the end of 1998, Russia's GDP had fallen by almost half since
1990.
The severity of Russia's economic problems, and the seeming
inability of a succession of governments to solve them, have raised numerous
questions about the painful reforms Russia's people have endured since the
collapse of communism. This chapter examines the main factors behind Russia's
economic development since the end of the Soviet Union. It begins with a brief
review of key events from the Soviet period that influenced the initial transition,
then considers the successes and failures of the reformist government in 1992
and 1993. In 1994 and 1995, the government was no longer a reformist one,
but it did complete the first macroeconomic stabilization and large-scale
privatization. In 1996-1998, reform ideas were again much discussed, and some
were even attempted, but their accomplishments fell short of their goals.
In August 1998 financial disaster struck.
The August 1998 crisis caused great turmoil in Russia and
hurt the welfare of its people badly. It is possible that the crisis will
stimulate more realistic economic and political thinking, but in truth the
main shortcomings of Russia's economic policy have long been known. A fundamental
problem is that the Russian government has never achieved a fiscal balance.
On the one hand, state revenues are declining because of an ineffective and
widely ignored tax system. On the other hand, the government has failed to
reduce and rationalize government expenditures. As a result of a lasting and
large budget deficit, short-term government debts accumulated to a level that
Russia's creditors no longer considered sustainable. The state debt service
became excessive not primarily because of the size of the debt, but because
of high interest rates caused by a badly functioning capital market.
Economically, the solution to Russia's problem was obvious.
For years, the government and international financial institutions had made
reasonable proposals to simplify the tax system, to broaden its base by abolishing
exemptions, and to reduce the top tax rates. Other areas where there was general
agreement on at least the broad contours of needed reforms included curbing
abusive government interference; protecting property rights, including the
private ownership of land; subjecting natural monopolies to market regulation;
reinforcing the rule of law; and improving the social safety net.
The adoption of these and other widely discussed measures
could have saved the Russian people a great deal of suffering. The key question
is why hardly any of them were undertaken. Our answer is that the rent-seeking
interests in Russian society were so strong that they overpowered concern
for the common good.[1] Moreover, the competition among the rent seekers was
so fierce that they could not halt their behavior but drove themselves to
financial collapse.
By rent seeking we mean the attempt to make money from the
government, either directly through state subsidies or indirectly through
government regulations.[2] For much of the period since 1991, the history
of economic reform in Russia can be best understood as a struggle between
reformers trying to create a normal market economy and rent seekers trying
to make money on market distortions. We focus in this chapter on what the
most important forms of rent seeking were, and how and why they evolved. In
our conclusion, we comment upon three aspects of the Russian transition: the
design of the reforms, the efficacy of international assistance, and the politics
of economic reform.
ECONOMIC ASPECTS OF THE SOVIET COLLAPSE
The demise of the Soviet Union had multiple causes, but serious
economic imbalances and distortions were certainly among the most important
of them. Soviet finances collapsed in 1991, as the union republics stopped
sending tax revenues to Moscow. The Soviet government faced a huge budget
deficit, but international financing dried up when the Soviet Union was no
longer
able to service its foreign debt. In late 1991 the central
government lived on little more than the emission of money. To make matters
worse, the union republics started issuing their own ruble credits without
any coordination with the Soviet State Bank: the more money any republic issued,
the larger share of the common Soviet GDP it obtained.
This huge issue of credit would have caused hyperinflation
had not most prices remained state controlled. Instead, inflationary pressures
took the form of devastating shortages of nearly all goods. In the fall of
1991 food stores were typically empty, and whenever goods were delivered,
long lines of customers appeared. For most workers it made little sense to
earn money when one then had to spend hours queuing to use it. The idiosyncratic
regulation of most prices led to incredible distortions: commodity prices
were extremely low, often less than 1 percent of world prices, while industrial
consumer goods were grossly overpriced.
The foreign trade regime aggravated these economic distortions.
The Soviet Union essentially had a special exchange rate for every major good,
and the differences between these rates were large. During the period of President
Mikhail Gorbachev's partial economic reforms, the number of Soviet enterprises
with the right to engage in foreign trade skyrocketed from 213 in 1988 to
almost 20,000 in 1990.[3] With the right connections, these enterprises could
acquire oil or metals at low Soviet state prices, obtain export licenses and
quotas from foreign trade authorities, and sell the commodities abroad at
the much higher world prices.
The Law on Cooperatives of May 1988 had made it legal to establish
freely operating private enterprises, but the rest of the economy remained
highly regulated. Many private trading cooperatives were set up by state enterprise
managers together with politicians, state officials, and shrewd businessmen.
One technique they favored was to buy commodities at low controlled prices
from the state enterprises they managed and to sell them at market prices
for private gain. Commercial banks became the most prominent new free-wheeling
cooperatives.
The so-called red directors - state enterprise managers who
flourished in the midst of the economic crisis because of inconsistent state
regulations - belonged to the old communist elite, but their behavior was
copied by new bankers, traders, and others. As Michael Dobbs put it:
There was a fin de regime atmosphere in Moscow in the spring
of 1991, and bureaucrats were lining up to jump ship before it was too late.
. . . Many members of the elite were now discovering that they could maintain
their privileged positions in society even without ideology. . . . Why drive
a Volga when you could be driving a Mercedes?[4]
In effect, the economic nomenklatura opted out of the socialist
system for a partial market economy, leaving the Soviet elite split and politically
vulnerable. This extraction of resources from the socialist economy virtually
guaranteed the breakdown of the Soviet economic system. Ordinary Russians
noticed who in the old elite had stood up against the Soviet system: since
the red directors ensured the collapse of the Soviet Union, they were widely
perceived as sensible heroes who understood that a market economy was necessary.[5]
But while these early proponents of a partial market economy
had become quite rich, they still wanted more. They were prepared to fight
for their privileges using their connections and fortunes - but not for a
liberal market economy with real competition. Grave-diggers of the old Soviet
system, these rent seekers were also the harshest enemies of radical reforms
aimed at establishing a level playing field.
Russia at the end of communism has often been described as
an institutional vacuum, but that is not quite true. Many institutional anomalies
incompatible with a market economy lingered. Relative prices were enormously
distorted; multiple and highly varied exchange rates persisted; monetary emission
was virtually unconstrained; interest rates were set at low nominal levels
in spite of rising inflation; entrepreneurship was subject to rigorous licensing;
myriad regulations persisted on the books. Ironically, little in the economy
was free except for banking. The government no longer owned or controlled
everything, but real private property rights had yet to emerge. State enterprise
managers tended to pilfer whatever public property they could. And most political
institutions were too weak to stop them.
AN ATTEMPT AT RADICAL ECONOMIC REFORM, 1991-1993
In a speech to the Russian Congress of People's Deputies on
October 28, 1991, President Boris Yeltsin announced his intention to move
the country from the Soviet economic system toward a market economy. Yeltsin's
main proposals were adopted as a guideline for the government's economic policies
by an overwhelming majority of the deputies a few days later. One week after
that, Yeltsin abolished the old Soviet branch ministries and appointed a new
type of government with an economic reform team headed by liberal economist
Yegor Gaidar. Yeltsin, Gaidar, and the young liberals who now led many ministries
made no secret of their intention to build a Western-style market economy
in Russia as fast as possible.[6]
Although the communists were discredited after the abortive
hard-line coup in August 1991, the young reformers encountered vicious criticism
from the outset. Even before the reforms had been launched, Vice President
Aleksandr Rutskoi ridiculed the leading reform ministers as ``small boys in
pink shorts and yellow boots.''
The reformers focused on getting state finances under control
and drew up a balanced budget for the first quarter of 1992. Another priority
was to liberalize prices, domestic and foreign trade, and entrepreneurship,
but resistance to these changes was particularly fierce. Some of the arguments
made against the reforms were patently absurd. Rutskoi claimed, for example,
that, ``The liberalization of prices without the existence of a civilized
market requires strict price control. . . . In all civilized countries such
strict controls exist.''[7] Behind such bizarre statements, however, lay the
interests of the so-called industrialists - managers of large state firms.
And few among the public had enough understanding of a real market economy
to judge the accuracy of such statements.
The key to understanding this highly antagonistic period is
the events of 1992 - the year the rich and powerful made their big money.
In the spring of 1992 the state price of oil was 1 percent of the world market
price; the domestic prices of other commodities were about 10 percent of world
prices. Managers of state companies bought oil, metals, and other commodities
from the state enterprises they controlled on their private accounts, acquired
export licenses and quotas from corrupt officials, arranged political protection
for themselves, and then sold the commodities abroad at world prices. Their
gains can be calculated easily by multiplying the average price differential
by the volume of commodities exported and deducting export taxes. The total
export rents were no less than $24 billion in the peak year of 1992, or 30
percent of GDP, since the exchange rate was very low that year. The resulting
private revenues were accumulated abroad, which led to massive capital flight.
A second way to get rich was to borrow money from the Central
Bank of Russia. In 1992 the bank gave enormous credits at subsidized rates
of 10 percent or 25 percent a year (at a time when inflation was 2,500 percent
a year). Viktor Gerashchenko, also the last chairman of the Soviet State Bank,
gave bank credits as a favor to well-connected businessmen. In 1992 alone,
the net credit issue of the Central Bank of Russia was 32 percent of GDP.
Directed credits to enterprises amounted to 23 percent of GDP. While these
benefits were less concentrated than export rents, they made Russia's bankers
rich.
The bankers, for their part, argued that the credit issue
was ``Keynesian,'' that is, that it would expand demand and support industrial
production. In fact, the bankers cared little when Russia's industrial production
plummeted in the wake of hyperinflation caused by excessive credit issue.
The reformers never managed to get control over the Central Bank of Russia.
Georgy Matiukhin, Gerashchenko's predecessor as chairman, reported in his
memoirs how he was ousted from the bank in June 1992 because he insisted on
raising the absurdly low interest rates contrary to demands from Ruslan Khasbulatov,
the speaker of the Supreme Soviet (the old semi-democratic Russian parliament).[8]
A third way of making a fortune in the transition period was
through import subsidies. In the winter of 1991-1992, there was great fear
both inside and outside Russia that the country would suffer famine. Under
such a threat, the reformers could not abolish the existing import subsidies
for food. The subsidies meant that an importer only had to pay 1 percent of
the going exchange rate when he purchased essential foods. After importing
them, he could sell the foods relatively freely on the domestic market and
pocket the subsidy for himself. These imports were paid for with Western ``humanitarian''
export credits, which were added to Russia's state debt. The total value of
the import subsidies was assessed at 17.5 percent of Russia's GDP in 1992
by the International Monetary Fund (IMF). These rents were highly concentrated
among a limited number of traders in Moscow, operating through the old state
agricultural monopoly companies.
The total gains from these three activities amounted to no
less than 71 percent of GDP in 1992. (This is a gross number, so the net gains
to several thousand people involved are significantly smaller, but the concentration
of income was extreme, and the revenues were huge in 1991 and 1993 as well.)
In a few short years, Russia went from having an income differentiation close
to the European average to having one of much higher Latin American proportions.
Other rents, while significant and harmful, were much smaller.
Direct state subsidies, mainly to agriculture, the coal industry, and large
enterprises, for example, were 10.8 percent of GDP in 1992 (see Figure 1).
Much has also been written about the economic impact of the Russian Mafia.
If by Mafia one means ``an industry which produces, promotes, and sells private
protection,''[9] we can estimate revenues from racketeering by focusing on
the retail trade, whose total sales amounted steadily to one-third of GDP.
In 1992 a standard protection fee was said to be 20 percent, but not all businesses
paid for protection. If we assume that the average protection revenues were
10 percent of total retail sales, the total annual revenues from protection
would amount to 3 percent of GDP.[10] Moreover, protection is a comparatively
labor intensive occupation, which means that net revenues per person must
have been much less in racketeering than in the other rent-seeking activities
mentioned above.
The rent seekers - state enterprise managers, bankers, corrupt
officials, and commodity traders - were well organized and politically influential.
Even so, after initial defeats the reform government made amazing headway.
Gradually, price and export controls were eliminated, bringing Russian commodity
prices closer to world prices. The dysfunctional ruble zone was broken up,
and each of the former Soviet republics established its own national currency
by late 1993.[11] Subsidized credits were abolished in late September 1993
by government decree, and by November 1993 Russia had positive real interest
rates. At the end of 1993 the exchange rate was fully unified, eliminating
the last import subsidies. In parallel, the privatization of small enterprises
was successfully undertaken, and large-scale privatization was under way.
The economic and social costs of these changes were great, but in late 1993
the reformers had accomplished so much that the reforms appeared irreversible.
There are several explanations of why fundamental reforms
that seemed impossible in the spring of 1992 were successfully undertaken
in late 1993.[12] Several rents declined for reasons beyond the control of
politics. First, as people and enterprises learned not to hold money in any
form, the velocity of money rose, which reduced the inflation tax. Therefore,
the budget deficit could no longer be financed with the emission of credits.
Second, as the media exposed various forms of rent seeking and people learned
more about how a market economy operates, the public grew much less tolerant
of unjustified subsidies. Third, a majority of the Russian voters expressed
support for radical economic reforms in a referendum in April 1993. This gave
the reformers a strong boost. And finally, the dissolution of the Congress
of People's Deputies in September 1993 created a temporary political vacuum
that offered reformers (but also the rent seekers) uncommon opportunities
to advance their agenda.
At the same time, a number of developments went against the
tide of reform. At the end of January 1992 President Yeltsin issued a decree
declaring the complete freedom of domestic trade. Instantly, tens of thousands
of Russians took to the streets in the big cities and started trading all
sorts of goods at whatever prices they could command. They also threatened
the interests of established traders with their effective competition. Alas,
after only three months, Moscow's Mayor Yuri Luzhkov prohibited free street
trading. Mayors of other big cities followed suit, and this brief interlude
of free enterprise in Russia came to an end. In May 1993 reform foes acted
on regional demands for comprehensive licensing of all firms, which further
blocked the free development of enterprise.[13]
The political support for the reforms expressed in the April
1993 referendum did not endure. Russians had anticipated a large decline in
economic output and consumption, but when a new round of inflation began,
many attributed the primary blame to the reformers who had liberalized prices
- not to those who had issued more money. The reformers suffered a severe
setback in the parliamentary elections in December 1993, forcing the departure
of reformist deputy prime ministers Yegor Gaidar and Boris Fedorov. Anatoly
Chubais, a lone reformist, stayed on as deputy prime minister in charge of
privatization.
Yet the red directors received an even worse blow in the elections.
Their leading organization, the Russian Union of Industrialists and Entrepreneurs,
had sponsored the political party Civic Union. Although the Civic Union was
perceived as a leading political force in the second half of 1992, it received
only 2 percent of the popular vote. The declining political power of the red
directors was reflected in shrinking benefits given to them by the government.
LINGERING REFORMS BUT NO REFORM GOVERNMENT, 1994-1995
The exit of all the reformers except Chubais from the government
led to a widespread expectation of significant reversals in the reform policies,
but in fact there was little change in economic policy in 1994. Prime Minister
Viktor Chernomyrdin wanted neither reform nor reversal. Inflation declined
and privatization proceeded, but few institutional reforms were undertaken:
leading ministers were primarily lobbying for privileges for their favorite
enterprises.
The budget balance was gradually being undermined. On ``Black
Tuesday,'' October 11, 1994, the exchange rate of the ruble fell precipitously
by 27 percent. By this time, the exchange rate had assumed a real economic
meaning to many Russians. In response to a popular outcry against economic
mismanagement, Yeltsin sacked his leading economic policy makers, apart from
Chernomyrdin. At long last, central banker Gerashchenko was dismissed. Chubais
was given the reins of macroeconomic policy as first deputy prime minister.
In 1995, for the first time, the Russian government and the
Central Bank pursued a coordinated economic policy aimed at macroeconomic
stabilization. The government halved the fiscal deficit to 5.4 percent of
GDP, mainly by reducing all kinds of enterprise budgets in the consolidated
state budget from 10.5 percent of GDP in 1994 to 3.4 percent of GDP in 1995
(see Figure 1). This was an extraordinary blow to a number of interest groups,
reducing rent seeking to only 8 percent of GDP.
In the spring of 1995 Russia concluded a full-fledged standby
agreement with the International Monetary Fund with substantial financing.[14]
By the summer of 1996, financial stabilization had been attained. Inflation
dropped to 22 percent in 1996 and to 11 percent in 1997.
Russian bankers were divided over the issue of stabilization.
Until the summer of 1995, the Association of Russian Banks pressured the government
and the Central Bank for subsidized credits. This, unfortunately, only led
to continued high inflation. Opposing financial stabilization, the Association
engineered the ouster of Tatyana Paramonova, acting chair of the Central Bank,
in the summer of 1995. When the interbank market dried up in the fall of 1995,
however, financially strong banks limited their trade to each other and excluded
weak banks that they did not want to receive any state support. The strong
banks benefited from the sale of cheap bank assets as one bank bankruptcy
followed another. From 1991 until 1997, the Central Bank rescinded the licenses
of more than 700 banks. The unity of the Association of Russian Banks had
been broken.
The other big economic event of this period was the completion
of the privatization of almost 18,000 large and medium-sized enterprises through
vouchers. Officially, more than 70 percent of the economy - measured as a
share of GDP - now belongs to the non-state sector. Many complaints have been
raised about privatization; a common one is that the old management has acquired
too much ownership. Studies show, however, that only 18 percent of the shares
of privatized large and medium-sized enterprises belonged to the old managers
in 1996.[15] When one considers that the state managers practically owned
public enterprises before privatization, the current situation should be seen
as a considerable reduction in the extent of their ownership.
Another complaint is that enterprise restructuring was too
limited. In fact, 33 percent of large and medium-size enterprises changed
management between 1992 and 1996, and about 25 percent of Russia's large and
medium-sized enterprises have gone through substantial enterprise restructuring.[16]
In our view, the insecure status of private property rights (including land
ownership) and excessive state regulation of the economy are much more responsible
for current economic problems in Russia than imperfections in the privatization
process. Local authorities continue to harass entrepreneurs with arbitrary
taxation and numerous inspections, and businessmen still have limited legal
recourse.
A third complaint is that privatization has led to a concentration
of wealth. Almost all of Russia's biggest companies have been traded freely
on an open stock market, and the total market capitalization has vacillated
between 5 and 20 percent of GDP from 1996 to 1998. This means that the market
value that state enterprise managers got from the voucher privatization of
their enterprises was only between 1 and 4 percent of GDP in total, compared
with 71 percent of GDP through export rents, import subsidies, and subsidized
credits in 1992. Thus, the concentration of wealth was not caused by privatization
but by other forms of rent seeking. The fact that the privatization process
was comparatively transparent and visible undoubtedly contributed to public
resentment of it: the average Russian generally overestimated the value of
industrial plants, for example, while not realizing the huge volumes of money
passing through financial markets. Nonetheless, the political consequences
of this popular illusion are real - and harmful.
A fourth criticism concerns a special ``loans-for-shares scheme''
that was introduced in 1995 for the privatization of a limited number of very
large enterprises. The movers behind this scheme were not red directors, but
some new bankers, notably Vladimir Potanin of Oneximbank and Mikhail Khodorkovsky
of Menatep. The government's dilemma was that too many large enterprises remained
state-owned, even after the voucher privatization was completed in the summer
of 1994, and it had proven difficult to sell enterprises for money in cash-strapped
Russia. Stock prices were tiny in relation to asset values, and large sales
of additional stocks would have further depressed stock prices. The idea arose
to sell large blocks of state shares through open auctions; it was thought
that this would not depress stock prices, although the offering prices would
be current market prices. Unfortunately, the auctions became closed, and the
offering prices almost equaled the closing prices. As a result, Oneximbank
seized control of Norilsk Nickel, the huge metallurgical company, and Sidanko,
an oil company. Menatep took over Yukos, the oil company; Boris Berezovsky
of the Logovaz car dealership got the Sibneft oil company at a very low price.
The loans-for-shares scheme attracted great public criticism,
even though only fifteen enterprises were sold and not all the loans-for-shares
privatizations were profitable for the auction winners. Only the four deals
mentioned above were really economically significant. And these privatizations
hardly changed the system; they only transferred the benefits of management
theft from some red directors to some new capitalists (and tarnished Chubais's
reputation). When Oneximbank took over Sidanko, it announced that the prior
management had siphoned off $350 million a year from the company. Presumably
Oneximbank's top managers started doing the same. Still, the total cash flows
that could be expropriated from these companies were well below half a percent
of GDP.
The importance of the reforms between 1994 and 1995 should
not be exaggerated. A government of industrial lobbies ruled. Prime Minister
Chernomyrdin secured extraordinary benefits for his creation, the Gazprom
natural gas monopoly, granting it extensive tax exemptions at the end of 1993
amounting to some 1-2 percent of GDP. First Deputy Prime Minister Oleg Soskovets
secured tax exemptions for the metal industry amounting to about 2 percent
of GDP. Soskovets also supported the National Sports Fund, which got the right
to import alcohol and tobacco tax-free. The Fund soon became the leading importer
of these goods to Russia. These benefits amounted to another 2 percent of
GDP. The agrarian lobby successfully resisted the privatization of land and
the deregulation of agriculture. The rent seekers had regrouped to seek new
forms of rents, notably tax exemptions. Nonetheless, the size of these rents
was far less than they had been in 1992-1993, and they were increasingly tax
exemptions rather than government financing. As massive tax evasion prevailed
and the tax system was arbitrary, however, it is not obvious what a normal
tax payment should have been.
Although Anatoly Chubais was the only significant reformer
left in the government, the reformers were publicly blamed for the ongoing
economic decline, while those in the government who unabashedly lobbied for
their private interests escaped unscathed. The parliamentary elections in
December 1995 dealt another blow to the reformers. The communists reemerged
as a serious political threat, mainly because the reformers were split into
too many parties.[17] In January 1996 President Yeltsin sacked his last reformist
minister with the oft-quoted words: ``Chubais is guilty for everything.''
THE STAGNATION OF REFORM, 1996-1998
As Russia entered 1996, a new fear of communist revenge dominated
Russian politics. Most anticommunist forces joined hands to counter that threat.
This offered a new position of privilege to the so-called oligarchs, essentially
new businessmen who had benefited from the loans-for-shares deals. The elections
highlighted the political importance of money and owner control over media.
Media magnates Vladimir Gusinsky and Boris Berezovsky (who controlled the
TV channels NTV and ORT, respectively) emerged as major political forces.
And the election results confirmed that the new Russian businessmen had gained
real political clout. One reflection of their new power was that the top bankers
nominated Vladimir Potanin to be first deputy prime minister, and Berezovsky
became deputy secretary of the Security Council. Both aroused such controversy
that they were soon ousted: Potanin lasted about six months, Berezovsky, twelve
months.
Nineteen hundred and ninety-six was a year of no reform. The
government contained no significant reformer, and the political will to reform
was missing. The government let the budget deficit rise to 8 percent of GDP
in 1996, and the real yields of its treasury bills exceeded 100 percent a
year before the presidential elections in June 1996, as the government tried
to sell more than the market was prepared to buy. The treasury bill market
became a source of rent seeking for bankers, since only some privileged people
were allowed to buy treasury bills for much of 1996.
The restless Moscow elite soon became frustrated with a government
that did nothing to resolve the country's mounting economic problems. In response
to calls from a broad political spectrum for a new reform government, Yeltsin
reappointed Chubais as first deputy prime minister in March 1997. Joining
Chubais in the cabinet was Boris Nemtsov, the successful reformist governor
of Nizhny Novgorod. Their reform offensive, however, ended abruptly in July
1997. The new businessmen were no more prepared to accept free markets than
were the old red directors. In July 1997 Berezovsky and Gusinsky turned against
the reformers in the government with a vengeance because they had initiated
an open auction of Svyazinvest, the telecommunications holding company. The
new capitalists were as committed to rent seeking as the old red directors
had been; they demanded their due from the government as payback for supporting
Yeltsin in the 1996 presidential elections. In October 1997 Berezovsky worked
with the communists and Prime Minister Chernomyrdin to increase the budget
deficit in an apparent attempt to undermine the reformers in government.
The Asian financial crisis started to hurt Russia in late
October 1997. Since Russia had just decided to increase the budget deficit,
the government failed to tighten its fiscal policy until February. By then,
interest rates had again risen to more than 100 percent a year. Only in late
March 1998 did Yeltsin sack his passive Prime Minister Chernomyrdin; one month
later, he appointed a reformist government under Sergei Kiriyenko. By then,
however, the crisis was so severe that even a government with sufficient parliamentary
support - which Kiriyenko did not have - would have had difficulty carrying
out the necessary reforms.
Russia's financial problems had been a long time in the making.
For years, the country had maintained an excessively large budget deficit.
Its fast-growing, short-term government debt could not be sustained. As creditors
withdrew, interest rates rose repeatedly above 100 percent a year. And at
the same time that Russia badly needed capital inflows, red tape and arbitrary
taxation rendered its enterprise environment cumbersome, deterring both domestic
and foreign direct investment.
In July 1998 the Russian government concluded an agreement
with the IMF on significant and swift budget deficit reductions. Yet four
major interest groups continued pushing their country toward the abyss. First,
the big oil barons, including Boris Berezovsky, who wanted lower production
costs, campaigned for a ruble devaluation, although they knew that this would
lead to the bankruptcy of most banks and create other serious problems.[18]
Second, in July 1998 the Russian State Duma refused to accept
a government proposal to move from a valued-added tax (VAT) based on actual
payments to one based on an accrual basis. Had it been adopted, the change
would have led to the taxation of barter, which is now exempt from Russian
VAT taxation. Nor would the Duma agree to transfer some government revenues
from the regions to the federal treasury. These two votes by the Duma were
the real trigger of the ensuing financial collapse.
Third, the regional governors strongly resisted the transfer
of any of their funding to the federal government. Regional revenues have
held steady at about one and a half times as large as the federal revenues,
and the regions spend slightly more than 2 percent of GDP on enterprise subsidies.
Because these subsidies are disbursed by the governor in a discretionary fashion,
they all but invite criminals to run for election as regional governors.
The fourth group that contributed indirectly to the financial
collapse was the state bureaucracy, which doubled in size in the midst of
economic crisis: an incredible 1.2 million bureaucrats (almost 2 percent of
the labor force) were added from 1992 to 1998. The result is an extraordinary
degree of bureaucratic interference in enterprises that deters investments
and entrepreneurship.
It is easy to condemn the behavior of these groups as socially
irresponsible, but in fact their actions were consistent with what their recent
experiences had taught them: that the most ruthless and cunning rent seeker
is the most successful; that the government was only bluffing when it warned
of economic ruin; and that in an economic environment that changes all the
time, one must seize all opportunities as soon as they appear.
The Russian economic crisis also had an important international
dimension. The years 1996 and 1997 saw substantial foreign capital inflows
into Russia, but these were almost entirely portfolio investments in stocks
and bonds. Foreign portfolio investments skyrocketed from $8.9 billion in
1996 to $45.6 billion - or 10 percent of GDP - in 1997.[19] Foreign direct
investment in 1997 was only $6.2 billion, and it fell to $2 billion in 1998.
At the peak of the stock market in 1997, foreigners might have owned as much
as 30 percent of the market capitalization of some $100 billion. The total
stock of treasury bills in the summer of 1998 amounted to some $70 billion,
of which foreigners held at least $25 billion.
All these inflows, however, actually encouraged capital flight
of about $20 billion in each of the years 1996 to 1998, while capital outflows
had subsided in 1994 and 1995. Rising capital outflows are a strong indication
of increasing rents. Hence, the foreign portfolio investments contributed
both to rent seeking and to the magnitude of the Russian financial crash.
The loans to the Russian government diminished the need for the Russian state
to collect taxes or to cut subsidies. The loans from the IMF and the World
Bank were contingent on sound economic policies, but the contingency appears
to have been ineffective, possibly because the much larger private portfolio
investments were unconditional. Many Russian businessmen made big money by
cheating foreigners or by seizing the assets of minority shareholders by any
means possible (from transfer pricing to the straightforward seizure of assets
to not servicing bond debts). Therefore, these inflows were counterproductive
both to corporate governance and to reform. Opportunities for rent seeking
appear to have dwindled after these inflows stopped in July 1998, but it is
too early to tell whether this change represents a real adjustment on the
part of government officials and Russian businessmen - or simply a lull while
the rent seekers identify new opportunities.
STRATEGIC ECONOMIC PROBLEMS
The ultimate purpose of an economy is to produce economic
growth, but Russia's economy has experienced significant contraction since
1990. While disputes over statistics make precise assertions difficult, the
trendlines are quite clear: with the exception of 1997, the Russian GDP has
fallen steadily for a decade. This steady decline can no longer be blamed
on temporary factors (see Figure 2), but on fundamental, long-term problems
that ultimately brought about the financial crash of 1998.
First, while every viable state must obtain revenues to finance
essential government activities, the Russian government for years has spent
more than it has collected in taxes. The Russian tax system is inconsistent
and arbitrary: tax collection absorbs much of the government's attention and
hampers many productive activities, but in the end taxation provides little
state financing. Second, the government has failed to control and rationalize
its expenditures; it often does not pay (or is late in paying) its commitments,
while large unjustified expenditures are disbursed. Third, markets of all
kinds still function badly due to excessive regulation and the absence of
the effective rule of law. This leads to high transaction costs, limited competition,
and various financial and monetary problems.
These economic problems have one dominant cause: the fact
that those who made substantial fortunes on inflation, regulations, subsidies,
and other rents continue to oppose the effective development of a competitive
market economy.[20] The state as the representative of a common public interest
is weak; the state as a bureaucratic impediment to productive economic activity
is ubiquitous - a phenomenon Andrei Shleifer and Robert Vishny have termed
``the grabbing hand.''[21] The key question for the future is whether the
Russian state can make the transition from stimulating rent seeking to encouraging
profit seeking.
An Ineffective Tax System
The Russian tax system is an unfortunate combination of the
old Soviet tax system, hasty and partial reforms from 1992, and subsequent
changes of dubious legality often motivated by rent seeking - all enforced
with large measures of inconsistency and sheer incompetence. While politically
well-connected businessmen often escape taxation, many small entrepreneurs
are forced out of business by confiscatory tax rates. Yet despite the high
rates, the system collects little actual revenue.
Although declining tax revenues and growing budget deficits
are the topics of frequent and alarmist news reports in Russia, total revenues
have fallen only moderately - from 36.8 percent of GDP in 1993 to 32.8 percent
in 1998 - if one includes as government revenues the federal budget, all the
regional budgets, and extrabudgetary funds like the pension fund (see Table
1). In 1997 Russia's total state revenues as a share of GDP were slightly
larger than in the United
States, but they were low by European standards, where the
average is close to 50 percent of GDP. The average for other Commonwealth
of Independent States countries, however, is slightly lower than in Russia,
and it is the least reformist countries that maintain large state revenues.[22]
While Russia's formal tax rates do not appear to be excessively
high, the country's tax laws do not define profits in the Western sense or
permit deductions for many legitimate business expenses. Indexing taxes for
inflation has also not been adopted. Taking inflation into account, the effective
profit tax rate in Russia may have been as high as 77 percent in 1992 and
50 percent in 1994-1995.[23] The system is also quite complex: Russia has
about 200 different taxes, most of which generate little revenue. Six main
taxes account for about 75 percent of all revenues of the consolidated state
budget.
Because the tax base is so narrow, a limited number of taxpayers
pay huge taxes. Almost two-thirds of taxes are paid by industry, while only
a tiny percentage of total revenues is collected directly from individuals.[24]
The system suffers from a dangerous bias toward corporate taxation, especially
taxation of manufacturing, and it discriminates against investment and production
in favor of consumption. Even so, according to estimates by U.S. Treasury
officials, an estimated 50 percent of the total VAT was not even collected
in 1996, due to numerous exemptions, reduced rates, and lax enforcement. Tax
exemptions are granted more on the basis of political and personal connections
than for reasons of public policy. Individual income taxes and property taxes
are still collected primarily through enterprises, as they were in the communist
era. The system offers taxpayers little or no incentive to pay taxes; the
risk of penalties hardly changes whether one pays taxes or not.
In the post-Soviet states, lower state revenues seem to be
clearly correlated with faster recovery in GDP. The post-Soviet state is such
a monster of arbitrary intervention that it can only be controlled if its
resources are severely reduced. To stimulate growth, a government must accept
a moderate level of tax revenues - 25 percent of GDP at most.[25] Subsidies
need to be minimized to reduce harmful state intervention. Unfortunately,
a statist approach has persisted in Russia, and the IMF has continuously supported
this policy of high taxes and ruthless tax collection. In our view, Russia
needs to cut taxes to boost production, in the expectation that economic growth
will eventually reverse the temporary shortfall in tax revenues.
Excessive and Unjust Public Expenditures
Russia's public expenditures are large in comparison with
other countries of the former Soviet Union, and Russia's budget deficit remains
considerable (see Table 2). The huge state debt service is paid for by the
federal government. Even so, regional and local budgets as well as extrabudgetary
funds have expanded at the expense of federal expenditures in recent years.
During the period of high inflation (1992-1994), the Russian
government (and the
governments of many other transition economies) boosted social
expenditures as a share of the GDP, but did not render them more efficient.
During those three years, contrary to public perceptions, social spending
increased by more than 5 percent of GDP. In parallel, expenditures of regional
budgets, measured as a share of the GDP, also grew rapidly, mainly because
of increased subsidies and social spending. As a result, in 1994 social expenditures,
including subsidies for housing and public transport, exceeded 50 percent
of general governmental expenditures (probably for the first time in Russia's
history).[26]
Unfortunately, these increases did not mean that the funds
were spent efficiently or fairly. By 1994 only 12 percent of all social transfers
(excluding pensions) went to the poorest 20 percent of the Russian people.[27]
By 1996 the wealthiest 30 percent of all households received no less than
70 percent of social transfers. Housing subsidies have held steady at 4 percent
of GDP - almost one-quarter of all social spending - although they primarily
benefit wealthy households with large apartments in cities.
Another concern is the prevalence of producer subsidies and
nontargeted forms of social protection. A significant share of Employment
Fund expenditures, for example, was used not for unemployment benefits but
for enterprise subsidies. In 1995, according to officials with the Ministry
of Labor and Social Affairs, approximately one-third of the resources of the
Social Insurance Fund (contributions to the Social Insurance Fund amounted
to 5.4 percent of the total wage bill) was allocated to so-called compulsory
tourism - that is, hidden subsidies to a noncompetitive network of boarding
houses, holiday resorts, and recreation centers inherited by Russia from the
Soviet era.
While regressive transfers go to the wealthy and the large
administrative bureaucracy works for its own advantage, a substantial share
of the Russian population - 38 percent in January 1999 - lives below the poverty
line. But even if they were not so inefficient or socially unjust, Russia's
huge expenditures remain too large to be sustained.
Poorly Functioning Markets
The battle to liberalize the Russian economy has been a protracted
one. Although prices and trade have been liberalized, state intervention remains
both pervasive and arbitrary. The market does not yet function well. Russia
ranks very low on several liberalization indices,[28] and corruption is pervasive.
In the Heritage Foundation index, which comprises the largest number of countries,
Russia ranks 106 among 160 countries in terms of economic freedom, while the
Fraser Institute index puts Russia at 102 among 114 countries.[29] In the
index of corruption perceptions compiled by Transparency International, Russia
was reckoned to be the 10th most corrupt out of 85 countries in 1998.[30]
Prices and markups are still high, the choice of goods is limited and their
quality is not impressive, and regional price differentials are sizable. Particularly
strong resistance to liberalization has come from the energy, agriculture,
and foreign trade sectors. Yet even if competition is limited, there are no
longer significant shortages of goods and services as there were in the Soviet
past.
Most Westerners are struck by the degree of regulation persisting
in Russia. Virtually all economic activities are subject to licensing, and
multiple licenses are usually required. More than sixty state agencies inspect
businesses, but instead of enforcing the strict regulations, state inspectors
attempt to extort bribes. Much new legislation, particularly on environmental
protection, seems more likely to offer new opportunities for bribe taking
than for improving public policy. And the only recourse most businessmen have
is to file an administrative complaint with the local authorities.
One consequence of the limited deregulation is that Russia
has few enterprises and very few small enterprises.[31] The number of registered
small private enterprises actually fell from 900,000 in 1994 to 810,000 in
1996. By 1997 the total number of legally registered enterprises had reached
only 2.7 million, about one enterprise per fifty-five Russians. By contrast,
the successful reform countries Poland and Hungary have already attained the
normal Western ratio of one enterprise per ten people.[32] The paucity of
enterprises is a result of a hostile enterprise environment that limits competition;
it explains why Russia has attracted little foreign direct investment.
Russia also suffers from poorly functioning financial markets.
Ordinary Russians do not trust banks (and for good reason), but keep most
of their savings - an estimated $40 billion - in hard-currency cash. In August
1998 most Russian banks closed down at least temporarily, and many Russians
who did have their savings in banks lost most of them. The Central Bank wants
to eliminate more than 700 banks, almost half of the total. The banking crisis
imposes additional fiscal pressures on the government, as some banks will
have to be recapitalized to restore the payments system. Meanwhile the real
sector (that is, the nonfinancial sector) of the economy suffers from a poor
payments system, excessive financial risks, and a limited supply of credits,
undermining the prospects for investment-driven economic recovery.
Recent historical experience in Central Europe indicates that
a gap of 10 percent a year between banks' lending and borrowing rates is the
norm immediately after stabilization.[33] In Russia, however, this gap has
remained greater than 20 percent a year, even before the outbreak of the financial
crisis in October 1997. It is likely to stay at about that level. The legal
system is much weaker in Russia than elsewhere in Central Europe, making the
collection of debts more cumbersome and expensive. Collateral is scarce, since
little private property is held in the form of land. Information about borrowers
is more scarce and less reliable in Russia than in Central Europe. Banking
skills and the ability to assess creditworthiness are rare. And the crime
rate is much higher in Russia than in Central Europe (the murder rate is as
much as five to ten times higher). For all of these reasons, Russian banks
demand larger margins - and they can do so because of the limited competition.
Even so, the Russian banking industry has entered a period of depressed profits,
consolidation, and bankruptcies.[34]
While the banks have big financial problems, the situation
with business enterprises is hardly better. Financial discipline at the enterprise
level is lax, and it is exacerbated by byzantine bankruptcy procedures, poor
legal means to enforce creditor claims, and a weak court system. The results
are mounting arrears of many kinds and the proliferation of payments in kind.
Monetization is low and it is not advancing. At the time of
high inflation, it was natural that the monetization (measured as M2 in relation
to GDP[35]) fell sharply from the high Soviet level of forced savings to barely
13 percent in 1993. It dropped further to about 10 percent in 1995, when the
eventually successful stabilization attempt was launched (see Figure 3). The
surprise is that the monetization has hardly risen after 1995, although inflation
was brought under control. By comparison, in 1995 successful Central European
reform countries such as Poland, Slovenia, and Hungary had a monetization
with M2 amounting to 30-40 percent of GDP. Monetization in most post-Soviet
countries, though, persists at about as low a level as in Russia.[36]
An explanation of the low level of monetization is that barter
and various forms of nonmonetary forms of payments are expanding. The share
of payments in Russian industry undertaken through barter rose from 6 percent
of all sales in 1992 to 54 percent in August 1998, according to the Russian
Economic Barometer, a regular poll of managers of Russian industrial enterprises
(see Figure 4).[37]
At the same time, plenty of money surrogates have emerged,
so that only one-quarter of interenterprise transactions are conducted with
money. The most common form of money surrogates are so-called offsets, which
function like this: If an enterprise has not paid its taxes, it offers the
government some products or services instead. If the government accepts, the
tax delinquent has in effect extracted a government contract by not paying
taxes. Moreover, through an offset an enterprise can avoid competition and
boost its prices.
The standard communist explanation of why barter is so prevalent
is that the economy suffers from a shortage of money. The typical suggested
remedy is additional emissions of currency - but this confuses supply with
demand. There is little demand for money because many enterprises prefer barter
and money surrogates to payments in cash, while other businesses are too weak
to demand payment in money. If the supply of money increased while the demand
remained low, the result would only be inflation.
The standard Western explanation of barter is that it and
other forms of noncash payments are motivated by tax avoidance, which seems
supported by polls among businessmen.[38] Russia's value-added tax (VAT),
in particular, is based on payments, not on invoices or deliveries on an accrual
basis (as is typical in the West). Hence, companies that receive little or
no payments in money are exempt from most of their potential VAT burden. For
the Russian government and the IMF, one of the most important reforms that
could be adopted would be to assess VAT on an accrual basis to reduce the
incentives to barter in the current tax code.
Yet tax avoidance is not the whole explanation of the prevalence
of barter. The same polls showed that 40 percent of the barter trade was perceived
as involuntary. Typically, larger industrial enterprises compel smaller firms
to accept payment in products they do not want.[39] Barter is most common
among large enterprises producing intermediary industrial goods that can be
sold easily - construction materials and metals, for example. It is clear
that these manufacturers have chosen barter partly because it distorts prices
and changes relative prices.
Clifford Gaddy and Barry Ickes have pointed out that the noncash
economy is growing, not shrinking. The system is well-entrenched, with strong
incentives for many to maintain it. The noncash economy is beneficial both
to value-detracting and to raw-material producing companies, while the household
sector loses in consumption and the government loses real tax revenues.[40]
The essence of the post-Soviet noncash economy is the reluctance of large
enterprises to adjust to market conditions at the expense of consumers (who
get shoddy goods), the government (which cannot collect taxes), and politically
weaker enterprises (which do not get paid in money). A transparent and competitive
monetized economy offers no particular advantages for large enterprises. By
contrast, relations with high government officials are crucial for an enterprise's
success in a noncash economy, and large enterprises typically have greater
access to senior state officials.
A good example of this phenomenon is Gazprom, the natural
gas monopoly that is Russia's biggest and richest company. Gazprom receives
payment in money for only one-tenth of its domestic deliveries, although the
firm clearly has the clout to demand more. Because Gazprom produces more natural
gas than it can sell on an ordinary market and has minimal marginal costs,
the firm uses barter to facilitate price discrimination and discounts. Gazprom's
close links to the government also allow it to leverage larger and more secure
benefits than it probably could earn in a competitive market.
Offsets are by their nature discretionary negotiations between
big businessmen and government officials about large amounts of money, a process
naturally imbued with corruption. Regional governments appear to be most corrupt,
accepting 60 percent of taxes in money surrogates. Local governments might
not have much clout against big companies, but even so they only accepted
43 percent of their revenues in money surrogates in 1996, suggesting they
tried hard to get real money.[41] The federal government received about 25
percent of its revenues in offsets, which is an indication that the federal
government is less corrupt than regional governments.[42] Money surrogates
also comprise a substantial part of the regional and local expenditures -
no less than 39 percent in 1996.[43] Thus, money surrogates not only distort
prices and tax revenues but also divert public expenditures away from social
spending toward public-works projects and enterprise subsidies.
Barter is also an important mechanism of management theft.
In the spring of 1998, coal miners staged large strikes to demand that the
government pay them months of back wages. But many of the mines in which these
miners worked had already been privatized, and the government had already
paid subsidies to the mines. Investigations showed that the mines received
only two-thirds of the price their customers paid for the coal. The remaining
one-third disappeared into the pockets of middlemen connected with some mine
managers, who cheated both their own workers and other mine owners. As a result
of the subsidization of the coal industry, it has become not only inefficient
but thoroughly criminalized.[44]
Thus, in almost every respect, the ongoing barterization of
the Russian economy represents a serious regression. It implies demonetization,
tax evasion, and the rule of big, old enterprises over small, new enterprises.
Both workers and shareowners suffer from its consequences: the only winners
are a small group of big enterprise managers. By avoiding money payments,
they reassure themselves that their personal relations with government officials
and each other remain decisive. Thus, barter and money surrogates conserve
the power structure in industry as well as the production structure. Little
modernization and restructuring are likely in this environment.
WHERE IS RUSSIA GOING?
The Russian economy has gone through a decade of economic
contraction. Economic policy is characterized by a duality: on the one hand,
Russia wants to catch up with the developed world by embracing a liberal reform
agenda. On the other hand, strong rent-seeking interests oppose reforms that
would eliminate their particular advantages based on connections to power.
Ironically, even as the role of the state is declining, the efforts of rent
seekers to make money on the state effectively give the government less to
redistribute, reducing rents more than output.
The current degree of government intervention in Russia is
extraordinary by any international standard, and it is not likely to be sustained.
Therefore, the government administration will have to be cut, as has happened
in most other post-Soviet states. The degree of effective regulation will
fall accordingly.
Similarly, the Russian government cannot continue to spend
considerably more than it collects in taxes. Sooner or later the government
must undertake a fundamental tax reform. A broad public consensus favors a
fundamental tax reform leading to a system with a limited number of broad-based
taxes with low tax rates of 20 percent or less. Similar tax reforms have been
adopted in other former Soviet republics, such as Estonia, Georgia, Kazakhstan,
and Kyrgyzstan.[45] In July 1998, after years of discussion, the State Duma
incorporated many of these ideas in a new tax code. Even the Primakov government
proceeded with the reduction of tax rates.[46]
Whatever happens with tax reform, state revenues are likely
to decline in the short term. After the 1998 financial collapse, however,
Russia has hardly any access to financing. It may get some additional loans
from international financial institutions, additional privatization, or the
refinancing of debt service, but selling Russian government bonds will be
difficult for years to come. Even the inflation tax cannot reap much revenue
because of the limited monetization. The key problem will be reducing the
budget deficit at a time of declining state revenues. The Russian government
will be forced to reduce sharply its expenditures, including those for state
administration, enterprise and housing subsidies, and various nomenklatura
benefits. In most of the post-Soviet states that have already done all this,
the shrinking of government expenditures makes rent seeking less attractive.
As the economy becomes more transparent, the incentives for entrepreneurship
and profit seeking grow.
But is this politically feasible - or will the beneficiaries
of the partial early reforms continue to block the necessary next steps? The
key determinant for Russia's future is how rent seeking will evolve.[47]
The peak of rent seeking occurred in 1992, when the main rents
were subsidized credits to enterprises (23 percent of GDP), export rents (30
percent), import subsidies (17.5 percent), and direct budget subsidies (10.8
percent), for a total of 81 percent of GDP.
By 1995 rents had plummeted. Subsidized credits and import
subsidies were gone in 1994, when export rents contracted to about 3.7 percent
of GDP.[48] Enterprise subsidies fell sharply in 1995 to 3.4 percent of GDP
(see Figure 1). We may include 0.5 percent of GDP in rents from the loans-for-shares
privatizations. Still, the narrow rents we focus on amounted to only about
8 percent of GDP.
Export rents continued falling, but they might still have
been 2 percent of GDP in 1997. Enterprise subsidies recovered slightly to
4.2 percent of GDP in 1997. Here, however, we need to include foreign portfolio
investments in our definition of rent seeking, since they were in effect free
money, appropriated by ruthless businessmen as a consequence of a poor legal
order or government inaction. We include enterprise bonds (about 2 percent
of GDP in 1997), stock investments (about 4 percent), and excessive returns
on treasury bills (about 3 percent). Thus, these amounted to 15 percent of
GDP in rents in 1997 - almost a doubling of the rents from 1995, although
our calculations do not include tax exemptions, the benefits of authorized
banks, and gains from barter and nonpayments.
The financial crisis of August 1998 eliminated the rents related
to foreign financing, as well as the excessive returns on treasury bills.
The only remaining rents are enterprise subsidies and some refinancing of
banks - less than half a percent of GDP. Hence, the financial crisis seems
to have cleaned out many rents and possibly prepared the ground for a low-rent
economy. Figure 5 presents an approximation of the development of rents in
Russia in the 1990s.
The sharp reduction of rents means much less money can be
spent buying politicians and officials, reducing the incentives to distort
economic policy to the benefit of rent seeking. The forces for rent seeking
are also being dissipated: the red directors, for example, were a dominant
political force as late as 1993, but they have now been partly replaced by
or merged with Russia's new big capitalists. The capitalists are split themselves:
a few top businessmen can reap private gains from discretionary state intervention,
but most of them demand lower taxes and more freedom, plus the protection
of a well-functioning legal system. Even the leading rent seekers have fought
each other since July 1997. They suffered badly from the financial collapse
of August 1998. No longer able to extract large rents, they have that much
less available to corrupt government officials and politicians.
The regional governors appear to be the greatest remaining
hurdle to a normal market economy. In recent years the regions have steadily
gained authority at the expense of the federal government. As automatic members
of the Federation Council (the upper house of the Russian parliament), regional
governors have a final say in Russian legislation. Their power is reflected
in the relative increase in the budgetary resources and decisions controlled
by them. As regional budgets account for two-thirds of the revenues of the
consolidated state budget, Russia has become the most decentralized federation
in the world.[49] Regional governments are likely to be much less constrained
by declining revenues than the federal government.
The powerful regional governors oppose a large and intrusive
federal government, but they do value federal transfers - as well as their
own power to intervene in the economy, and their regional regulations disrupt
the unified Russian market. Federal government transfers to the regions have
been quite small, peaking at 3.4 percent of GDP in 1994 and then declining.[50]
Most regions are net recipients. Ironically, transfers tend to go to the regions
that voted against the government in both the 1993 and 1995 elections - not
to the regions with the greatest social need - thus showing that these transfers
reflect the weakness of the federal government.[51] The regional transfers
are not likely to increase as a share of GDP because of the falling federal
tax revenues, but the regional governors nonetheless defend them forcefully.
To date the regional governors have been notorious for controlling
certain prices, licensing and subsidizing enterprises, allocating administrative
credits provided by regional banks, controlling exports from their regions,
and generously subsidizing housing, utilities, and transportation. Fortunately,
some of these practices have stopped. But regional governors are eager to
control the licensing of all private enterprises and to mandate inspections
of them by multiple local authorities - both to generate bribes and to intimidate
entrepreneurs. The federal authorities could possibly impose a far-reaching
deregulation from the center, but many argue that the federal government lacks
the power to do this in the short run.
Another concern is that no less than 60 percent of all taxes
at the regional level are being paid in nonmonetary forms, typically in offsets.[52]
An enterprise that offers to provide goods or services instead of paying its
taxes is in effect asking for a public contract without competing for it.
These practices breed further corruption, making the regional governments
appear more corrupt than the more constrained federal government.
In summary, the increased political weight of the regional
governors is likely to limit state expenditures as a share of GDP. A reduction
of the revenues of regional budgets as a share of GDP, however, is necessary
to persuade regional authorities to reduce subsidies and to improve the targeting
of social benefits. For the time being, regional governments are likely to
remain far too intrusive in enterprises. After the so-called oligarchs have
been cut down to size, the regional governors appear to be the main impediment
to successful reforms.
CONCLUSION
In Russia today, all the standard features of the communist
command economy are gone. The government no longer determines who manages
enterprises; what they produce, sell, or buy; or what prices they set. A pluralist
structure of ownership has been established. From early 1996 until the summer
of 1998, Russia had a reasonably stable currency. Since the summer of 1998,
however, Russia has been in a serious financial crisis. Despite many improvements
over what existed before, the emerging Russian market economy still displays
serious imperfections. State ownership is more extensive than in almost any
Western state, and even fully privately owned enterprises are heavily dependent
on the state. State power is exercised with more arbitrariness than would
be accepted in the West, and businessmen have little legal recourse in their
relations with the state.
The main themes of the Russian reform agenda have been deregulation,
stabilization, and privatization. Unfortunately, nothing conclusive can be
said about the design of the reforms, since so little was actually implemented.
Deregulation of all kinds is essential to end rent seeking. The reformers
fought for the liberalization of commodity prices, but they lost. As the domestic
commodity prices were kept artificially low, exports could not be liberalized.
The fear of starvation in the winter of 1991-1992 made it politically impossible
to unify the exchange rate, which would have eliminated import subsidies.
The reformers tried to liberalize domestic trade but with limited success.
Gaidar pushed for considerable freedom for enterprises, but his efforts were
rebuked. The preceding bizarre freedom of private banks persisted.
On fiscal policy, the reformers started out well, opting for
a balanced budget in early 1992. Various quasi-fiscal expenditures, however,
such as subsidized credits and import subsidies, became the dominant fiscal
problems, with the Central Bank as the main culprit. Only after two years
did the Ministry of Finance acquire elementary control over state expenditures.
The Central Bank was independent of the government, but it was not interested
in monetary stability, and it bred macroeconomic disaster.
One of the greatest misperceptions of the Russian transition
is that privatization was the primary means by which personal enrichment occurred.
Contrary to the common understanding, Russian enterprise ownership is reasonably
well distributed, but it has not become effective ownership. Privatization
is no alternative to deregulation, though it might facilitate deregulation
in the future. Nor has privatization been an effective impediment to rent
seeking. In the financial crisis of 1998, the Russian tycoons did not behave
like capitalists who cared about the value of their property, but like rent
seekers who thought only of the short-term cash flow.
After the government failed to establish the main pillars
of a sound economic policy, little else succeeded. In the first years of transition
social expenditure rose sharply as a share of GDP, and even now social transfers
remain much too large. Russia's social expenditures still benefit the old
nomenklatura more than they provide any social safety net for the needy. With
populist demagogy, the old establishment has even boosted the regressiveness
of Russia's social transfers.
In Russia, ``industrial policy'' has been a code word for
demands for subsidies. Three industries have secured the most: the coal industry,
agriculture, and the military-industrial complex. As a result, trade in their
products has become criminalized, because subsidies are not only an indicator
of rent seeking but also a strong inducement to organized crime.
There has been considerable international involvement in Russia's
economic reforms. The IMF has been the dominant force for several reasons.
Its main mission is to promote macroeconomic stabilization, which was new
Russia's most pressing problem. The IMF also has a lot of money to offer for
concrete programs; its narrow agenda provides for a clear focus; and it has
been more active than other international actors. The IMF's finest achievement
was the standby agreement in the spring of 1995 that led to stabilization,
mainly due to a cut in enterprise subsidies of no less than 7 percent of GDP
(see Figure 1). It was a highly daring action, as it occurred just before
parliamentary and presidential elections, and the only real guarantor was
Anatoly Chubais, first deputy prime minister. The IMF and the World Bank were
important forces behind the deregulation of foreign trade, which eliminated
most foreign trade rents.
The worst failure of the West was a sin of omission: not to
support the stabilization program in early 1992. If the West had sponsored
an IMF-like program then, it would have been possible to liberalize commodity
prices and exports, to unify the exchange rate, and to introduce market interest
rates from the beginning of 1992. The main blame for missing this window of
opportunity belongs to the U.S. administration, the decisive Western policy
maker at the time. The IMF, however, was guilty of advocating the maintenance
of the ruble zone in spite of the fact that fifteen mutually independent central
banks were all competitively emitting the same currency.
In the spring of 1996 the IMF concluded a three-year loan
program called an Extended Fund Facility (EFF) with Russia. The formal conditions
were reasonably firm, but the country was heading toward a budget deficit
of more than 8 percent of GDP and sold treasury bills at interest rates of
as much as 150 percent a year in real terms. This was a political rather than
an economic decision, intended to save President Yeltsin in the presidential
elections of June 1996. Saved he was, but at the expense of sound economic
policy. The EFF agreement set the stage for Russia's ensuing boom and bust.
The soft IMF approach convinced foreigners and Russians alike that Russia
was too big - or too nuclear - to be allowed to fail. The EFF signaled that
in Russia anything is allowed.
As of the spring of 1999, it is still early to judge whether
the IMF program of July 1998 was too small, too late, or never feasible. Yet,
in retrospect, it is difficult to believe that the IMF could ever have had
a decisive impact in Russia after April 1, 1992 - and no other international
organization came close to matching its efforts.
A broader issue is the politics of reform, which is primarily
a drawn-out struggle between reformers and rent seekers. Most advice given
to reform governments tends to disregard how constrained their feasible choices
really are, given the influence of powerful, rent-seeking interests. A common
fallacy is that technical assistance will teach bureaucrats do their jobs,
when the real problem is that many bureaucrats are corrupt and have no interest
in seeing their powers or revenues reduced. Nor is it realistic to believe
that a parliament that opposes private ownership will enact appropriate protections
thereof.
Reformers face many important choices, particularly at the
outset of reform. Before democratic governance has taken form, reformers must
act quickly and decisively from above, as President Yeltsin did after he effectively
assumed power in the fall of 1991. In November 1991 Yeltsin formed a government
that swiftly formulated a reform program. He pronounced this program in a
presidential speech to parliament, which voted to accept it. The missing element
was international financial support, since the West was preoccupied with securing
the Soviet debt, and was seemingly disinterested in Russia's future. Soon
rent seekers got the upper hand in domestic politics.
Compared with Poland, the Czech Republic, and the Baltic states,
all of which also launched radical reforms but received timely Western financial
support, Russia looks like a failure. Compared with Ukraine, which did not
try early reforms, however, Russia looks more successful. The reformers' failure
was their inability to mobilize the popular majority that supported radical
economic reform during the first year and a half of economic transition through
early parliamentary elections.
In the second period of reform (1994-1995), the reformers
could do little. In hindsight, the large-scale privatization hardly looks
so important that it warranted the presence of a key reformer such as Chubais
in the government. The stabilization of 1995-1996 appears less significant
today, since it was not sustained but led to a new bout of rent seeking. Presumably,
the reformers would have been better off politically had they declined to
serve in a deeply corrupt government.
In 1997-1998, several prominent reformers held high government
offices, but their reform proposals were obstructed by entrenched rent seekers.
That this would be the outcome was not obvious at the outset; after all, Chubais
had successfully stabilized the economy in 1995 with less political support.
But the reformers themselves are ambiguous in their views on government service
and international financial support. Boris Fedorov, for example, tends to
argue that IMF support is harmful when he is not in government - but favors
it as a lever against opponents when he is.
Russian reformers are learning to understand the new rent
seekers' mode of operation, which makes their approach more political and
less economic, and their political understanding is developing. Repeated failures
of reformers in coalition governments to implement reforms successfully made
many doubt the efficacy of reform from above at the current stage of development.
And a growing reformist opinion argues that a parliamentary majority in favor
of reform is necessary for real market economic reform. Russia is facing a
regional conundrum, and no clear understanding about how to deal with the
regions has arisen, making it unlikely that a solution will soon be found.
NOTES
1 Joel S. Hellman, ``Winners Take All: The Politics of Partial
Reform in Postcommunist Transitions,'' World Politics, vol. 50 (January 1998),
pp. 203-34.
2 In principle, rent seeking could also include social transfers
and public wages, but here we limit the discussion to rents extracted by businesses.
3 Anders Åslund, Gorbachev's Struggle for Economic Reform,
2nd ed. (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1991), p. 141.
4 Michael Dobbs, Down with Big Brother: The Fall of the Soviet
Empire (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1997), p. 373.
5 Boris Yeltsin seems to have shared this view. In his book
The Struggle for Russia (New York: Random House, 1994, p. 168), Yeltsin declared
that he believed more in middle-aged state enterprise managers than in his
reform ministers.
6 This section is largely based on Anders Åslund, How
Russia Became a Market Economy (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1995).
7 Aleksandr Rutskoi, ``Is There a Way out of the Crisis?''
Pravda, February 8, 1992.
8 G. G. Matiukhin, Ya byl glavnym bankirom Rossii (Moscow:
Vysshaya shkola, 1993), p. 69.
An additional reason for the lack of monetary restraint was
that the ruble zone persisted: each country had its own central bank that
issued ruble credits independently until the summer of 1993.
9 Diego Gambetta, The Sicilian Mafia: The Business of Private
Protection (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1993), p. 1.
10 Reliable data on protection fees are difficult to obtain.
These estimates are based on conversations with businessmen and economists
in Moscow.
11 Brigitte Granville, ``Farewell, Ruble Zone,'' in Anders
?slund, ed., Russian Economic Reform at Risk (London: Pinter, 1995), pp. 65-84.
Tajikistan, a marginal economy, continued using Russian rubles.
12 Anders Åslund, Peter Boone, and Simon Johnson, ``How
to Stabilize: Lessons from Post-Communist Countries,'' Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, vol. 26, no. 1 (1996), pp. 217-313.
13 Anders Åslund, How Russia Became a Market Economy,
p. 144.
14 A standby agreement is a standard IMF loan program for
one year based on a number of conditions concerning primarily budget deficit
and monetary expansion.
15 Joseph R. Blasi, Maya Kroumova, and Douglas Kruse, Kremlin
Capitalism: Privatizing the Russian Economy (Ithaca: Cornell University Press,
1997), p. 193.
16 Ibid., p. 203.
17 See the chapter by Michael McFaul and Nikolai Petrov in
this volume.
18 A good example of the arguments used by one leading oilman
is the interview with Vagit Alekperov, chief executive officer of Lukoil,
``Nuzhno ispol'zovat' opyt Yaponii. . . .'', Kommersant-Daily, November 11,
1998. Alekperov's suggestions included devaluation, lower taxes for the oil
industry (which had already benefited from substantial devaluation), price
controls, Central Bank credits for the oil industry, the inflationary emission
of money - and continued taxation of the general population.
19 Russian European Center for Economic Policy, Russian Economic
Trends: Monthly Update (Moscow: Russian European Center for Economic Policy,
February 10, 1998), Table 10.
20 Joel S. Hellman, ``Winners Take All: The Politics of Partial
Reform in Postcommunist Transitions.''
21 Andrei Shleifer and Robert Vishny, The Grabbing Hand: Government
Pathologies and Their Cures (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1998).
22 Vito Tanzi, ``Transition and the Changing Role of Government,''
paper presented at the IMF conference, ``A Decade of Transition: Achievements
and Challenges,'' (Washington, D.C., February 1-3, 1999), Table 5.
23 European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD),
Transition Report 1995 (London: EBRD, 1995), p. 88.
24 Russian Federation State Tax Service, monthly reports.
25 Vito Tanzi, ``Transition and the Changing Role of Government,''
p. 7.
26 Anders Åslund and Mikhail Dmitriev, eds., Sotsialnaya
politika v period perekhoda k rynku: problemy i resheniya (Moscow: Carnegie
Moscow Center, 1996).
27 Branko Milanovic, Income, Inequality, and Poverty during
the Transition from Planned to Market Economy (Washington, D.C.: World Bank,
1998), p. 113.
28 See, for example, Martha de Melo, Cevdet Denizer, and Alan
Gelb, ``From Plan to Market: Patterns of Transition,'' Policy Research Working
Paper 1564 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1996); European Bank for Reconstruction
and Development, Transition Report; and Bryan T. Johnson and Thomas P. Sheehy,
1996 Index of Economic Freedom (Washington, D.C.: Heritage Foundation, 1996).
29 Bryan T. Johnson, Kim R. Holmes, and Melanie Kirkpatrick,
1999 Index of Economic Freedom (Washington, D.C.: Heritage Foundation and
the Wall Street Journal, 1999), p. 331; James D. Gwartney and Robert A. Lawson,
Economic Freedom of the World: 1997 Annual Report, as published on the Internet
website of the Fraser Institute (www.fraserinstitute.ca), Exhibit 2-2.
30 Transparency International, ``The Corruption Perceptions
Index,'' as published on the Internet website of Transparency International
(www.transparency.de/documents/cpi/index.html), 1998.
31 A. Blinov, ``Maloe predprinimatelstvo i bolshaya politika,''
Voprosy ekonomiki, no. 7 (1996), p. 39.
32 Anders Åslund, ``Observations on the Development
of Small Private Enterprises in Russia,'' Post-Soviet Geography and Economics,
vol. 38, no. 4 (1997), pp. 191-205.
33 Biswajit Banarjee, Vincent Koen, Thomas Krueger, Mark S.
Lutz, Michael Marrese, and Tapio O. Saavalainen, Road Maps of the Transition:
The Baltics, the Czech Republic, Hungary, and Russia, IMF Occasional Paper
no. 127 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund, 1995).
34 M. E. Dmitriev, M. Yu. Matovnikov, L. V. Mikhailov, L.
I. Sycheva, E. V. Timofeev, and A. Warner, Rossiiskie banki nakanune finansovoi
stabilizatsii (St. Petersburg: Norma, 1996). In 1997 the Central Bank closed
more than 300 Russian banks.
35 M2 is defined as cash and bank deposits.
36 Yegor T. Gaidar, ``Taktika reform i uroven gosudarstvennoi
nagruzki na ekonomiku,'' Voprosy ekonomiki, vol. 70, no. 4 (April 1998), pp.
4-13.
37 Russian Economic Barometer, vol. 7, no. 4, p. 86.
38 S. Aukutsionek, ``Barter v rossiiskoi promyshlennosti,''
Voprosy ekonomiki, vol. 70, no. 2 (February 1998), p. 53.
39 Ibid., p. 55.
40 Clifford G. Gaddy and Barry W. Ickes, ``Russia's Virtual
Economy,'' Foreign Affairs, vol. 77, no. 5 (September/October 1998), pp. 53-67.
41 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development,
OECD Economic Surveys: Russian Federation 1997 (Paris: OECD, 1997), p. 181.
42 Andrei N. Illarionov, ``Effektivnost biudzhetnoi politiki
v Rossii v 1994-1997 godakh,'' Voprosy ekonomiki, vol. 70, no. 2 (February
1998), p. 24.
43 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development,
OECD Economic Surveys: Russian Federation 1997, p. 181.
44 Sharon LaFraniere, ``A Hotbed of Crime in Cold Siberia:
In Gang-Run Coal Land, Authorities Take Cover,'' Washington Post, January
7, 1999, p. A16.
45 Daniel A. Citrin and Ashkok Kilahiri, eds., ``Policy Experiences
and Issues in the Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet
Union,'' IMF Occasional Paper no. 133 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary
Fund, 1995).
46 Russia's current VAT rate of 20 percent is comparable to
that in other CIS countries and is only slightly higher than the European
Union average of 18 percent. A broad Russian consensus favors a sharp reduction.
Ironically, the IMF insists on keeping the VAT so high. The profit tax rate
of 35 percent was already low by international standards and was lowered to
30 percent in
1999. The Russian maximum income tax rate of 35 percent is
also not high by international standards, although it too should be reduced,
since hardly anyone pays at that rate. Reducing the income tax to a flat rate
of 20 percent is a common proposal, although the communists advocate higher
income taxes for the rich.
At 42 percent, the payroll tax is the highest tax rate and
a considerable reduction has been widely demanded. In spite of all the talk
of Russian protectionism, import tariffs remain low, averaging about 14 percent.
The elimination of offsets and tax exemptions for privileged companies and
agriculture are more controversial issues. In any case, tax evasion will inevitably
continue to flourish.
47 We take a narrow view of rents as caused through government
action, primarily direct or indirect government subsidies. We consider rents
as annual flows, not as stocks. We are only concerned with rents going to
enterprises, leaving social expenditures aside. Considering the arbitrary
tax system and collection practices, a correct tax standard can hardly be
established, which makes it impossible to assess the value of tax exemptions
appropriately, compelling us to disregard tax exemptions. They have probably
diminished slightly over time, because the total tax revenues have fallen
and tax exemptions have been strenuously opposed by reformers and the IMF.
For the same reason we leave the benefits from barter and offsets aside, which
have clearly increased over time. Monopoly rents tend to be estimated at 0.5-1
percent of GDP in a Western economy, and they are likely to be several times
larger in Russia, but they are difficult to estimate, which forces us to ignore
them. They have probably fallen over time, as regional price differentials
have contracted. We also leave aside racketeering fees, which appear to have
declined. We are looking at rent seeking from the cost side, while net revenues
are much smaller. An official may take a bribe of $10,000 as his private gain,
for example, to let somebody seize public assets worth $1 million, which is
the public cost. We try to avoid double counting, although we sometimes include
the financing of rents and sometimes disbursements.
48 Oil and natural gas prices were on average about one-third
of the world market price in 1995, but a free market price would probably
have been about two-thirds of the world market price, because of the high
transportation costs. Therefore, the export rent can be assessed at about
one-third of exports of oil and natural gas. In 1995 total Russian exports
of oil, petroleum products, and natural gas amounted to $39.3 billion, and
GDP was $357 billion (Goskomstat Rossii, Rossiiskii Statisticheskii Yezhegodnik
1997 [Moscow: Goskomstat, 1997], pp. 577, 582, 586; Brunswick Warburg, Russian
Monthly, Moscow, December 1998, p. 7).
49 World Bank, Fiscal Management in Russia: A World Bank Country
Study (Washington D.C.: World Bank, 1996).
50 Aleksei Lavrov, ``Fiscal Federalism and Financial Stabilization,''
Problems of Economic Transition, vol. 5 (May 1996), p. 87.
51 Daniel Treisman, ``Deciphering Russia's Federal Finance:
Fiscal Appeasement in 1995 and 1996,'' Europe-Asia Studies, vol. 50, no. 5
(1998), pp. 893-906; Daniel Treisman, ``The Politics of Intergovernmental
Transfers in Post-Soviet Russia,'' British Journal of Political Science, vol.
26, no. 3 (July 1996), pp. 299-335; Aleksei Lavrov, Mify i rify Rossiiskogo
byudzhetnogo
federalizma (Moscow: Magistr, 1997).
52 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development,
OECD Economic Surveys:
Russian Federation 1997, p. 181.